rectrectrectrectrectrectrectrectrect
rectrectrectrectrectrectrectrectrectrect
Picture Picture
Picture
Picture

   Quality Management                by A. Blanton Godfrey

Hidden Costs to Society

If we could see an estimate of every appliance's total life-cycle costs, we'd very likely make quite different buying decisions.

Earlier this year, I served on the committee for a doctoral candidate, Lars Sörqvist, at the Royal Institute of Technology in Sweden. Sörqvist's thesis concerned poor quality costing. It examined how companies currently estimate poor quality costs and explored some new ideas about estimating actual costs. It also expanded upon the concept of total losses due to a company's imperfect products and processes.

This theory, not completely new, relates to Genichi Taguchi's earlier definition of "loss to society" caused by poor quality. When I first     encountered this concept in the early 1980s, I found it hard to accept. At the time, one of the early papers went so far as to suggest that if a television picture was too good, children would watch too much TV, thereby resulting in a loss to society. But, as usual, Taguchi was ahead of his time, and now we're beginning to realize the far-reaching implications of this line of thought.

Sörqvist carefully defines five levels of poor quality costs. The first level comprises the traditional poor quality costs of rework, warranties, scrap, inspection costs and other visible internal and external failure costs. Normally hidden expenses he classifies as level two costs. These include invoice errors, unnecessary paperwork and wasted meeting times incurred by management. But level two costs also include chronic, routine problems that are easy to ignore and frequent, unthinking corrections that aren't captured by accounting systems.

In the third level, Sörqvist includes costs related to lost income. When marketplace goods and services fail to meet customers' needs or wants, substantial losses may occur. Although it's usually difficult to quantify them, these costs are real and often quite high. They may result in immediate loss of market share or goodwill as well as long-term market effects. Poor service in a hotel, for example, might not impact revenues from the customer's current stay, but the customer's refusal to return to that particular hotel could certainly impact future revenues.

Sörqvist's fourth level of poor quality costs includes losses incurred by customers. Such costs may or may not result in lost sales or market share, and may not even result in warranty costs. Competitors may incur the same losses, and customers may believe the costs are unavoidable.

These costs include early replacements (for example, light bulbs that last only a few thousand hours), incompatibilities with other equipment or software, items that are unnecessarily difficult to repair and other defects in design or workmanship for which customers end up paying.

But it's the fifth level that stretches the usual definitions of poor quality costs the farthest. These are the socioeconomic costs, losses that affect a community due to inadequate processes or products of companies, organizations or governments. These costs have become increasingly more obvious. They include products that can't easily be recycled and are harmful to the environment; manufacturing wastes that poison the air, land and water; and products with harmful side effects.

Many of these costs are only visible years later. The worldwide costs of DDT, lead-based paints, asbestos, pesticides, certain pharmaceuticals and industrial products are hard to estimate. Short-term benefits from these products invariably obscure long-term hazards. A drug with a serious side effect can create costs to society far beyond its obvious damage to the individuals using it.

For instance, society often overreacts to the drug and creates new laws requiring lengthy testing procedures that affect manufacturers of similar products for years to come. In the process, many useful new medicines are delayed or prevented from reaching the market, thus causing unnecessary deaths and suffering.

Governments create many of society's greatest losses. At local, state and federal levels, layers of needless work accumulate. Anyone who has responded to proposal requests from government agencies has glimpsed the enormous waste potential built into their processes. Anyone who has waited in long tollbooth lines has experienced the elaborate systems designed to collect thousands of dollars while squandering millions in valuable time.

It would be instructive to extend total life-cycle costs to include this fifth level. What if government agencies had to prove that the value of the information they collected was greater than the costs of collecting it? What if tollbooths stopped operating every time the combined value of commuters' waiting times exceeded the money being collected? If we could see an estimate of every appliance's total life-cycle costs -- energy use, maintenance and recycling cost -- we'd very likely make quite different buying decisions.

Perhaps we'd greatly intensify our quality efforts if we had accurate estimates of all five levels of poor quality costs and understood the true effect of improving our processes and products.

About the author

A. Blanton Godfrey is chairman and CEO of Juran Institute Inc. at 11 River Road, Wilton, CT  06897.

© 1998 Juran Institute. For permission to reprint, contact Godfrey at fax (203) 834-9891 or e-mail agodfrey@quality digest.com.

Picture

[Home Page] [Current] [ISO 9000 Database ] [Daily News] [Phil’s Journal]
[Quality Management] ['98 Past Issues] [Resources] [Advertising]
[Subscribe] [Guestbook]

Copyright 1998 QCI International. All rights reserved. Quality Digest can be reached by phone at (530) 893-4095.

Please contact our Webmaster with questions or comments.

Picture

e-mail Quality Digest